THE GLOBAL LAND GRAB: An Analysis of Extant Governance Institutions

Abstract

Headlines such as In Corrupt Global Food System Farmland is the New  Gold and Land Grabs in Poor Countries Set to Increase reflect the urgent tone of a  recent surge in media coverage on the ‘global land grab.’1 At first glance it appears that mainstream media is experiencing collective amnesia by decrying large-scale investments  in foreign land. It only takes a very cursory examination of colonial and imperial history  to realize that scrambles for rich lands have underpinned geopolitics for several hundred  years. However, this paper takes the position that both the driving forces behind current  land investments and proposals to manage their most deleterious effects combine to make  today’s global land grab distinct from those of the past.  

Although there is considerable research regarding the connection between land  grabs and globalization processes, little has been written about the land grab phenomenon  from a global governance perspective. This paper has three objectives, namely to (i)  probe the global processes that have led to the current global land grab; (ii) contribute to  the literature by identifying the governance responses that have surfaced in the wake of  this new phenomenon; and (iii) assess the characteristics of mainstream governance  approaches to land grabs. 

The discussion opens by defining ‘globalization.’ This theoretical groundwork will illuminate how incentives for land grabbing are based in an economic interpretation  of globalization. Next, a description of the global land grab is provided to highlight the  global processes involved in the current rush toward farmland. The dominant global  governance institutions aimed at disciplining land grabbing are then introduced, followed  by a review of the multiple voices that influence the policymaking process. Rather than  one specific institution governing land grabs, a messy configuration of regimes, or a  “regime complex,” governs land grabs. This paper applies the notion of a regime complex  to the extant governance institutions surrounding land grabs. Finally, through an analysis  of mainstream institutional responses, I argue that severe deficiencies exist within  conventional approaches to the governance of land grabs. A more realistic assessment of  the motivating factors behind land grabbing is necessary to adequately reign in forces that hinder poverty alleviation and rural development in targeted countries.


Globalization and Global Governance 

Globalization is a term applied to a range of contemporary processes; here,  globalization is understood as the emergence of a global marketplace. For Labonté and  Schrecker, globalization is 

a process of greater integration within the world economy through movements of goods and services, capital, technology, and (to a lesser extent) labour, which lead increasingly to economic decisions being influenced by global conditions…2 

The decade of the 1970s is often associated with the emergence of the  contemporary global marketplace. Despite the seemingly ad hoc nature of globalization, the interconnections materializing at this time were not inevitable. Rather, they were the  result of deliberate political choices such as the active support of trade liberalization and  financial deregulation measures.3 The perceived soundness of these measures served to  further entrench them over the coming years and by the 1990s, powerful Western  governments promoted an “intellectual blueprint” based on the indisputable benefits of  free markets and private ownership.4 Thus, a neoliberal paradigm has informed the course  of globalization over the past several decades. 

 

The Global Land Grab 

Borras and Franco define the global land grab as “a catch-all framework to  describe and analyze the current explosion of (trans)national commercial land  transactions related to the production and scale of food and biofuels.”5 The implications  of land grabs are diffuse. There is not one uniform “local” experience to draw upon but in  terms of the impacts on small-scale farmers in targeted countries the results are viewed as  problematic. History indicates that these types of investments will either have the effect  of driving farmers off their land in search of alternative work (often non-existent or  under-employment), or turning farmers into a class of workers on large-scale plantations  with a high risk of human rights violations.6 Moreover, as subsistence farming is the  foundation of many developing country communities, land grabs could restrict people’s  access to vital resources and plunge already poor populations further into poverty.  

Land grabbing has occurred for hundreds of years as cornerstones of colonial and  neocolonial practices: European colonialism encouraged the takeover of foreign farmland to produce crops like tea and tobacco for domestic consumption during the 19th century  and neocolonialism echoed these structures by pushing foreign fruit companies to set up  large plantations in Central America and Southeast Asia in the 20th century. While  acknowledging similarities to historical trends, many scholars, analysts and activists  believe that the current land grab is undeniably peculiar. A first indication of this  departure is the spectacular increase in investment in agricultural land that occurred in the  latter half of 2008. It is estimated that between 1997-2007, 1.9 million hectares (ha) of  land was expanded for cultivation. However, over the course of just a few months in  2008, foreign investors expressed interest in approximately 56 million ha of land with  agricultural potential.7 However, what truly differentiates the present trend of large-scale  land acquisitions from those of the past is its connection to three major crises of this  decade: the global financial crisis, the food crisis, and the energy crisis.

  

A perfect storm: the financial, food and energy crises  

There are three main reasons why land is being grabbed on a global scale: to  secure alternative energy sources, to strengthen domestic food security in import dependent countries and to increase the financial returns of large investors.8 The latter  two motivating factors essentially represent two sides of the same coin. Volatility in  commodity markets has, on the one hand, troubled countries that are heavily reliant on  food imports and, on the other, signaled profit making opportunities to financial investors.9 

The 2007-2008 financial crisis had a dramatic impact on food prices and the value  of agricultural land due to the interconnectivities between financial deregulation and commodity exchanges. Indeed, Ghosh argues that, “the global food crisis…is not  something that can be treated as discrete and separate from the global financial crisis.”10 The sustained price hikes in commodities from 2002-2007 were accompanied by a  financialization of commodity markets, which is explained as “a growing presence of  financial investors on commodity futures exchanges.”11 Ghosh describes how policies  introduced in the early 2000s opened up commodity exchanges to new financial players  who had previously been blocked from entry due to regulation that prevented market manipulation.12 When the financial crisis hit with the antecedent collapse of the U.S.  housing and derivative markets, investors were left searching for new areas in which to  channel their funds. As is pointed out by the World Bank, the financial crisis encouraged  a “rediscovery” of the agricultural sector by multiple actors.13 Cotula and Vermeulen also  note how the upward trend in commodity prices has increased returns on investment in production.14 This has translated into greater interest in owning land or owning shares in  companies that are involved in the production end of the value-chain. 

The influx of speculative investments by hedge funds, pension funds and banks in  commodity markets led some to argue that they were directly linked to a sharp increase in  the prices of staple crops. However, as the severity of the crisis increased, investors could  not sustain the same degree of speculative investment, and commodity prices quickly  experienced a sharp decline by mid-2008.15 In sum, the volatility of commodity prices  has exposed the food security vulnerabilities of heavily import-dependent countries and  the financial crisis drew financial investors’ attention to the profit making opportunities  presented by relatively unproductive, cheap land. These factors converged to increase purchases of land in the developing world.

The same forces that led to higher and volatile food commodity prices are also  behind unstable oil prices. The final element of this perfect storm that created favorable  conditions for land grabbing is the increasingly important role of biofuels as an  alternative to fossil fuels. The governments of the US, EU and Brazil have been actively  promoting the production of biofuels since the 1990s.16 By promoting policies geared  toward biofuel production, these states have increased incentives for land grabbing.  Corporations and other investors have been investing in biofuel production on a global  scale with substantial investments in the global South.17 For instance, estimates calculate that the EU relies on more than five million ha of land for biofuel production in the  developing world.18 The processes of land grabbing for biofuel development vary across  locales. Typically, internationally funded interests broker deals with state officials or  large landowners involving little or no contact with small-scale farmers who are working  the land. Peasants enjoying customary rights to the land are often illegally evicted, having  to settle for less fertile land or struggle to find alternative employment. Those who stay work on biodiversity-poor land as landless laborers. For example, in the Polochic Valley  in Guatemala, local communities are being forced off their land to make way for biofuel 

production.19 Growing interest in biofuels has impacted the global food supply, as it has  led to the allocation of land to produce biofuel crops and also diverted existing food  production toward biofuels.20 Ghosh believes that the constraints that biofuels have  placed on the supply of agricultural land for food production has been one of the most  important contributing factors for high food and grain prices.21 

The preceding discussion highlights the various global forces at play in the rush  toward agricultural land in the developing world. The neoliberal underpinnings of these processes have led to what McMichael deems “commodity fetishism,” the  commodification of food and fuel, which has worked to reframe agricultural land as a  highly desirable target for foreign investment.22 The recent surge in large-scale land  acquisitions is firmly grounded in complex globalization processes and thus presents  formidable challenges to effective global governance. As Headey et al. note, “biofuels are  here to stay, and energy and food prices have adjusted to a higher equilibrium, albeit with  larger volatility.”23 This suggests that the driving forces behind the global land grab are  not abating and signals the need to discipline the ‘frictions’ arising from globalization.24  

The global land grab: irredeemable disaster, risk or opportunity? Despite recognition that a global land grab phenomenon is underway, little  consensus on how to effectively evaluate, and thereby govern, global land grabs exists.  Non-state actors have drastically different interpretations about the impacts of, and  prospects presented by, global land grabbing. Groups like the Via Campesina that  represent poor peasants and small-scale farmers in developing countries believe that the  global land grab poses disastrous consequences for the wellbeing of communities,  ecosystems and the climate: 

Land grabbing – even where there are no related forced evictions – denies land for local communities, destroys livelihoods, reduces the political space for peasant oriented agricultural policies and distorts markets towards increasingly concentrated agribusiness interest and global trade rather than towards sustainable peasant/smallhold production for local and national markets.25 

Development agencies and think tanks such as the International Food Policy Research  Institute (IFPRI), the World Bank, the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO), the International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD), and the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) realize that there  have been extremely negative consequences associated with the recent surge of land  grabbing: the displacement of local populations; a reduction in food security;  environmental damage; loss of livelihoods; social polarization and political instability.26 Additionally, these agencies have identified the secretive manner in which land deals are  often conducted along with the targeting of countries with weak land tenure rights for investments as drawbacks.27 The International Federation of Agricultural Producers  (IFAP), which represents the interests of middle-income farmers in the developed world,  also takes a more pro-land grab stance.28 IFAP’s position on land grabbing can be traced  to the strength of commercial interests amongst its membership.29 Rather than calling for  a moratorium on land grabbing, supporters believe that if managed correctly, large-scale  land acquisitions can be ‘win-win.’ Discourse plays a powerful role in this debate. When  land grabs are framed as ‘risks’ there is an inherent recognition that if certain conditions  are met, they can be transformed into ‘opportunities’. This judgment effectively  legitimizes global land grabs. All that remains to be determined is how to ensure that land  grabs benefit all sides through effective governance measures. 

The Global Governance of Land Grabs 

A fundamental characteristic of global governance is the rise of non-state actors in  regulating issues that traditionally have been dealt with by state governments.30 As  McMichael notes, “the (neoliberal) institutional setting has shifted from a state-centric to  a global social landscape.”31 Expanding on this observation, Borras Jr. and Franco highlight how the shifting perceptions of the roles of civil society, the market and states  have led to the emergence of a “corporate social responsibility agenda.”32 This new  approach to governance has opened up decision-making from a limited group of elite  state members to participation from variety of actors. In addition to this shift, which has  intensified the complexity of the policy process, the density of international institutions  has increased as a response to the emergence of global problems.33 Although regulation  of the global land grab is nascent, this paper contends that this is an issue that will not be  governed by a distinct, elemental regime, but rather by an intermingling of institutions.  

As Chanda aptly points out, 

Globalization has been with us since the dawn of history, but the notion of trying to govern the interconnections that it has produced is a more recent phenomenon. Governance has thus developed slowly, lagging far behind the trade, travel, and interaction wrought by globalization.34 

Accordingly, the reactive nature of global governance institutions is also evident with  respect to land grabs. Discussions regarding the regulation of land grabs have developed  more slowly than the phenomenon itself. Two noteworthy reports have been released  over the last two years that identify visions for how land grabs ought to be managed:  Principles for Responsible Agricultural Investment that Respects Rights,  Livelihoods and Resources and Rising Global Interest in Farmland: Can it yield  sustainable and equitable benefits? The former is a collaborative effort between the  FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD, and the World Bank while the latter is solely a World Bank  publication. These high profile players recommend a soft law approach to regulating land grabs through Principles for Responsible Agricultural Investments (PRAI), reflecting the  growing popularity of instituting voluntary schemes in the face of global problems.35 

The PRAI report intended to open up the discussion over regulating land grabs for  commentary, suggestions, further research and analytical input from a wide variety of  stakeholders including civil society organizations, multilateral and bilateral donor  agencies, and all major investor categories.36 The authors hoped that the major recipient  countries of these investments would support the recommendations and help implement  them on the ground. The seven PRAI include: “Respecting land and resource rights;  ensuring food security; ensuring transparency, good governance, and a proper enabling  environment; consultation and participation; responsible agro-investing; and social and  environmental sustainability.”37 Ultimately, the goal of the PRAI is to be translated into  an agreement on codes of good or best practices and “actions for investors, governments,  donors and international agencies, at different levels.”38 

The World Bank report addresses criticisms about the PRAI that charge the  principles with promoting investor interest rather than helping vulnerable countries insulate themselves from the negative impacts of land grabbing.39 The report thus seeks  to identify how stakeholders can increase smallholder productivity and improve local livelihoods.40 It believes that land grabs can contribute to poverty alleviation through  three mechanisms: payments for the lease and purchase of land; the generation of  employment for wageworkers; and new opportunities for contract farmers.41 The authors  of the report believe that governments in target countries, investors, civil society, and international institutions must be actively incorporated into the decision-making process  in order to achieve positive outcomes with respect to land grabbing.  

The Bank calls on recipient countries to improve administrative structures,  provide infrastructure, clarify and secure local rights, and protect critical natural resources.42 Investors are considered to be highly sensitive to reputational risk and are  thus expected to engage in activities that minimize social dislocation and environmental  destruction. Industry-driven initiatives that promote best practices are deemed desirable  in this context, however, the involvement of host states is also perceived as necessary to  ensure the initiatives operate effectively on the ground. Civil society organizations (CSO) 

are called upon to educate local communities on their rights; provide specific assistance  in negotiation and monitoring; and perform a watchdog function to draw attention to noncompliance with existing policy or “globally agreed norms.”43 Finally, the Bank  regards international organizations as performing a bridging function that encourages  stakeholders to agree on a standard set of principles.44 

The PRAI and World Bank reports represent clear attempts at regulating land  grabs through typical global governance methods. The blurring of the public and private  spheres demonstrates the reliance on civil society actors to perform roles that were  traditionally expected of states as well as through the reliance on investors to self-regulate. Another prominent actor to consider in the global governance of land grabs is  the Committee on World Food Security (CFS), whose mandate is to improve the global  governance of food and consists of all FAO member states, non-governmental organizations, international agencies and the private sector.45 In October 2010, the CFS  launched an inclusive process to consider the PRAIs. The CFS is slated to develop a set  of voluntary guidelines on the Responsible Governance of Tenure of Land and  Other Natural Resources and will likely refer to the PRAI as a guiding framework.46 

The consultation process is underway and stakeholders are beginning to draft position  pieces in order to impact the direction of the guidelines. 

Despite mainstream progress toward governing land grabs, multiple alternate perspectives have surfaced, aimed at influencing the rapidly evolving policymaking  process. For groups who are concerned about poverty alleviation and rural development,  the mainstream approaches are short-sighted. For instance, Olivier De Schutter, United  Nations Special Rapporteur on the right to food, believes that increased investments in  agriculture will encourage the development of a market for land rights and promote a  shift toward export-oriented agriculture.47 Such a transition, he thinks, is unlikely to  support rural development and poverty alleviation, as it will encourage the development  of large-scale, mechanized forms of agriculture, which tend to employ fewer farmers than  traditional agricultural methods. As such, De Schutter proposes an alternative program  for agricultural investment, which he first presented to the Human Rights Council in  December 2009 and was aimed at influencing the discussion of land grab regulation at a  forthcoming G8 summit.48 De Schutter asks that land-related investments respect eleven  minimum human rights principles so states are not tempted to consider large-scale  agricultural investments from a purely economic standpoint.49 Some of these  recommendations include ensuring investment agreement revenues benefit local populations, promoting labor intensive farming systems, and requiring that investor  obligations are clearly defined and enforceable.50 According to Li, the human rights  approach has, “the potential to get closer to the structural dynamics of impoverishment” by forcing governance institutions to think more broadly about the impacts of land deals,  and to consider the impacts on livelihoods for current and future generations, rather than  focusing narrowly on the technicalities of a particular deal.51 

CSOs have also taken a human rights approach to the governance of land grabs. In  March 2011, CSOs representing farmers, nomadic pastoralists, indigenous peoples, fisherfolk, women, youth, and urbanites drafted proposals for the FAO Guidelines on  Responsible Governance of Land and Natural Resource Tenure.52 These CSOs argue that,  “[i]n order to have a clear normative standard about what responsible governance is, the  Guidelines should be based on the universal human rights framework.”53 During the same  timeframe, other CSOs representing farmers organizations, unions, religious  organizations, non-governmental organizations and other social movements gathered at  the World Social Forum 2011 in Senegal to develop the Dakar Appeal Against the Land Grab.54

This appeal represents a significant departure from the other perspectives mapped  above. These CSO groups call on “parliament and national governments to immediately  cease all massive land grabs current and future and return the plundered land”; they  demand “that governments, the Regional Unions of States, FAO and other national and  international institutions immediately implement the commitments that were made at the  International Conference on Agrarian Reform and Rural Development”; and that “states,  regional organizations and international institutions guarantee people’s right to land and support family farming and agro-ecology.”55 One major downside of the Appeal is that it  leaves no room to manipulate land deals to bring “benefits” to all involved.  

It is evident that a broad range exists with regards to the positions various  stakeholders are taking in response to the global land grab. Although, these views may be  considered equally legitimate from an academic standpoint, in the context of a world  defined by neoliberal globalization, those that align more closely with mainstream  neoliberal norms, such as the PRAI, are more likely to prevail within dominant global  governance institutions. 

 

The land grab regime complex  

The preceding discussion regarding the various approaches to the governance of  land grabs displays the difficulty of “decomposing” individual institutions surrounding  problems that are global in nature.56 According to Raustiala and Victor, the proliferation  of international regimes has led to a messy configuration through which various issues  are governed, labeled the “regime complex.”57 A regime complex is “an array of partially  overlapping and nonhierarchical institutions governing a particular issue-area.”58 Raustiala and Victor’s depiction of the regime complex provides an effective framework  for the study of messy configurations of global institutions. Three general characteristics  apply to regime complexes: path dependence; forum shopping; and the adoption of broad,  aspirational rules. These characteristics help explain how issues are governed globally  and why particular institutions gain traction within global governance systems. 

Raustiala and Victor maintain that because institutions do not develop in a  vacuum, they exhibit path dependency. This is explained as “extant arrangements in the  various elemental regimes will constrain and channel the process of creating new rules.”59 Indeed, the World Bank explicitly recognizes how institutions in other sectors as well as  at different levels of governance will interact with and inform regulations over land  grabbing. It identifies the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI), the  African Union’s Framework and Guidelines on Land Policy, the Equator Principles, and  the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development Investment Guidelines as  providing fruitful models for the governance of land grabs. These models also involve the  governance of resource use across territorial boundaries and have the potential to create  significant environmental and social externalities.60 De Schutter points to the Agreement  on Trade-Related Investment Measures as well as regional trade agreements such as the  North American Free Trade Agreement as disallowing countries to impose performance  requirements on foreign investors.61 

Clearly, innumerable preexisting regimes have informed the character of  dominant approaches such as the PRAIs and the World Bank report. Aside from the  institutions listed above, the rules for land grabbing are bound by deeply entrenched  norms. Most notably, the land grab debate takes place within a neoliberal paradigm.  Three constraints that are rooted in neoliberal norms illustrate how path dependency may  impact the governance of land grabs. First, institutional arrangements have evolved  around land rights, which promote neoliberal ideals such as efficiency in credit and in  land markets.62 It is argued that the “Western based concepts of property rights” have largely informed the PRAIs as their emphasis is on securing tenure and land rights in  order to achieve “win-win” deals.63 A second constraint placed on the development of the  land grab regime includes the growing legitimacy of public-private partnerships, or the  increasing perception of the merits of transnational private authority. Again, this  emphasis is a reflection of what Sadler and Lloyd call a “theoretical framework of  ‘rolling-out’ neoliberalization.”64 A third consideration is the emerging biofuels complex.  The biofuels complex reproduces a “global ecology, whereby planetary resources are to  be managed through the application of the market paradigm to the environment (‘market  environmentalism’), reinforcing a growing ‘metabolic rift’, and the separation of people  and nature.”65 The treatment of land as a commodity, an attitude that is being accelerated  by global land grabbing, is an aspect of neoliberal policymaking that has increasingly  encouraged market mechanisms to be the “sole director of the fate of human beings and  their natural environment.”66 

Forum shopping is another conjecture of regime complexes. In the disaggregated  decision-making model typical of global governance, actors are able to seek out their  negotiating forum of choice. It is evident that powerful agribusinesses or hedge funds will  likely opt to support the principles espoused by the World Bank as opposed to those  developed at the World Social Forum, for example. The World Bank has a track record of  encouraging similar types of large-scale investment. Indeed, De Schutter points out that,  since the structural adjustment policies of the 1990s, it has consistently encouraged  developing countries to favor “inward foreign investment by cutting down administrative  requirements and consultations that might slow down or restrict investments.”67 Li believes that the World Bank’s work on land tenure and titling over the last two decades  has centered on creating a favorable legal environment for investors and that the World Bank’s focus has been to encourage investment to rural areas that “investors have thus far  avoided because they are too risky.”68 Logically, powerful corporations and states  involved in the investment side of land grabs are going to lend legitimacy to the PRAIs  which allow them to continue business as usual in an only slightly modified way.  Meanwhile, more radical forums that reject neoliberal policies tend to become  marginalized because their views are primarily attractive to those who are sidelined in the  current global system.  

Finally, regime complex theory contends that, “when the legislative agenda is  complex and contested, lawmakers often adopt broad, aspirational rules – delegating to  the process of implementation exactly how these rules will be interpreted and applied in practice.”69 Similarly, the World Bank report makes general calls to states, investors, civil  society and international institutions as to how to improve the regulation of land grabs  and defers the task of working out the details of these policies to the implementation  process. The PRAIs are equally vague, and are critiqued by De Schutter for not being  embedded in a “political analysis of how they might actually work in practice.”70 

Concluding Remarks 

According to Scholte, globalization is a highly political process, “global links are  venues of conflict and cooperation, hierarchy and equality, opportunity and its denial.”71 The foregoing analysis makes evident the power struggles associated with increasing transplanetary and supraterritorial connections typical of neoliberal globalization. Despite  decision-making becoming increasingly disaggregated in our current era, accountability  still remains in states’ hands, which can hinder far-reaching goals such as poverty  alleviation and rural development.  

The data show that most large-scale investments occur in areas that have poor  governance records and weak land rights protection.72 However, the PRAIs and the  World Bank report emphasize the responsibilities of host governments to ensure that  land-grabs are not harmful to local populations and generate wide scale benefits. Due to  this overreliance on host countries to strengthen governance institutions, the  implementation of the PRAIs and the World Bank report is deemed unlikely. In response  to the World Bank report Li warns,  

The formidable list of problems connected with large-scale land acquisitions that are identified in the report–problems that derive from the capacity of national and transnational capital in cahoots with rapacious regimes to wreak havoc on rural peoples’ lives–are reduced to ‘weaknesses in the institutional and policy framework’, technical issues that can ‘be addressed in the short term. This is a fantastic proposition.73 

States that are the primary targets of investment are unlikely to have the capacity to  strengthen their institutions or implement the governance conditions that the dominant  approaches perceive as necessary to benefiting local communities.74 In some cases it is  conceivable that states are also unwilling to uphold PRAIs, particularly if state  governments themselves are reaping financial benefits from these deals and competing  with neighboring countries for investment, thus being encouraged to engage in ‘race to  the bottom’ behavior.

The preceding analysis suggests that understanding the value of land, not as a  commodity, but as a “lifeline for the poorest rural households,” should inform the  direction of emerging governance institutions around land grabs.75 The importance of  establishing robust international rules and standards for land grabs is described by Cotula  and Vermeulen as serving a broader, and extremely pressing goal. It is seen as a  necessary step that, “the international community, including UN and Bretton Woods  institutions as well as international NGOs and concerned governments must take to  reinvigorate confidence in multilateralism.”76 In order to be effective, these rules must be  punitive enough to hold non-state actors and foreign governments to account. In their  current form, the PRAIs and the World Bank report are disingenuous in their assumptions  that host states will be able to implement the necessary changes to safeguard themselves  against land grabbing. If, as they claim, increasing smallholder productivity and  improving local livelihoods are their ultimate goals, they must engage in an honest  assessment of the situation. This would involve taking global power dynamics into  account and addressing the systemic factors that are placing the development prospects of  local communities at risk. Such an approach would require supporting alternatives to  neoliberal governance models. 

 

ENDNOTES

1 Stephen Leahy, “In Corrupt Global Food System Farmland is the New Gold,” All Africa, January 14,  2011 and Hilaire Avril, “Land Grabs in Poor Countries Set to Increase,” All Africa, September 8, 2010.

2 Ronald Labonté & Ted Schrecker, “Introduction: Globalization’s Challenges to People’s Health,” in  Labonté, Schrecker, Corinne Packer, and Vivian Runnels, Globalization and Health: Pathways,  Evidence and Policy (London: Routledge, 2009), 3. 

3 Ibid.

4 Ibid

5 Saturnino M. Borras Jr. and Jennifer Franco, Towards a Broader View of the Politics of Global Land  Grab: Rethinking Land Issues, Reframing Resistance, Netherlands: Initiatives in Critical Agrarian  Studies, 2010: 2. 

6 Daniel Shepard and Anuradha Mittal, The Great Land Grab: Rush for World’s Farmland Threatens  Food Security for the Poor, (Oakland: The Oakland Institute: 2009), 11. 

7 Klaus Deininger et al., Rising Global Interest in Farmland (Washington: World Bank, 2011), xxxii. 8 “Seized! The 2008 land grab for food and financial security” GRAIN, accessed March 20, 2011,  http://www.grain.org/briefings_files/landgrab-2008-en.pdf 

9 “The Global Economic Crisis: Systemic failures and multilateral remedies” United Nations Conference on  Trade and Development, accessed March 20, 2011, http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/gds20091_en.pdf, 23. 10 Jayati Ghosh, “The Unnatural Coupling: Food and Global Finance” Journal of Agrarian Change (10) 1  (2010): 72.  

11 United Nation Conference on Trade and Development, 23.  

12 Ghosh, “The Unnatural Coupling,” 78. 

13 Deininger, Rising Global Interest in Farmland, 1. 

14 Lorenzo Cotula and Sonja Vermeulen, “Deal or no Deal: the outlook of agricultural land investment in  Africa,” International Affairs (85) 6 (2009): 1237. 

15 Ghosh, “The Unnatural Coupling,” 79. 

16 Peter Dauvergne and Kate J. Neville, “Forests, food, and fuel in the tropics: the uneven social and  ecological consequences of the emerging political economy of biofuels” Journal of Peasant Studies (37)  4 (2010): 635.  

17 Borras Jr., “The Politics of Biofuels, Land and Agrarian Change.” Journal of Peasant Studies (37) 4  (2010): 577. 

18 Ibid., 577. 

19 Annie Bird, “Biofuels, mass evictions and violence build on the legacy of the 1978 Panzos Massacre in  Guatemala,” accessed on August 3, 2011, http://farmlandgrab.org/post/view/18354 20 Ghosh, “The Unnatural Coupling,” 73. 

21 Ibid., 72. 

However, there is a considerable degree of contention regarding how much biofuels have contributed to  rising food prices. Dauvergne and Neville point out that some sources attribute rising food prices to  biofuels by as little as two percent while the World Bank has found a 75 percent correlation.

22McMichael, “Agrofuels in the Food Regime,” 609.  

23 Derek Headey, Sangeetha Malaiyandi and Shengagn Fan, Navigating the Perfect Storm: Reflections  on the Food, Energy, and Financial Crises, (Washington: IFPRI, 2007): v. 

24 Anna Lowenhaupt Tsing, Friction: An ethnography of global connection (New Jersey: Princeton  University Press, 2005). 

25 “Stop Land Grabbing Now” GRAIN. Accessed on April 1, 2011, http://www.grain.org/o/?id=102.

26 “Principles for Responsible Agricultural Investment that Respects Rights, Livelihoods and Resources”  FAO, IFAD, UNCTAD and World Bank Group, Accessed on April 1, 2011, http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTARD/214574-1111138388661/22453321/Principles_Extended.pdf .

27 Deininger et al., Rising Global Interest in Farmland, xiv. 

28 Saturnino M. Borras Jr. and Jennifer Franco, “Towards a Broader View of the Politics of Global Land  Grab: Rethinking Land Issues, Reframing Resistance” ICAS May 2010, 5. 

29 Saturnino M. Borras Jr., Philip McMichael and Ian Scoones, “The politics of biofuels, land and agrarian  change: editor’s introduction,” Journal of Peasant Studies (37) 4 (2010): 585. 

30 Scholte 2002 and Fuchs 2005.  

31 Philip McMichael, “Agrofuels in the Food Regime,” Journal of Peasant Studies, (37) 4 (2010): 612. 32 Saturnino M. Borras Jr. and Jennifer Franco, “From Threat to Opportunity? Problems with the Idea of a  “Code of Conduct” for Land-Grabbing,” Yale Human Rights and Development Law Journal, 13  (2010): 507. 

33 Kal Raustiala and David G. Victor, “The Regime Complex for Plant Genetic Resources,” International  Organization (58) (2004): 277. 

34 Nayan Chanda, “Runaway Globalization Without Governance” Global Governance, 12 (2008): 119.

35 Jennifer Clapp, “The Privatization of Global Environmental Governance: ISO 14000 and the Developing  World,” Global Governance 4 (1998): 295. 

36 “Principles for Responsible Agricultural Investment that Respects Rights, Livelihoods and Resources,”  20. 

37 Deininger et al., Rising Global Interest in Farmland, xxvii. 

38 Ibid., 21. 

39 Deininger et al., Rising Global Interest in Farmland, 3. 

40 Ibid., 129. 

41 Tania Murray Li, “Centering Labor in the Land Grab Debate” Journal of Peasant Studies, (38) 2  (2011): 281. 

42 Deininger et al., Rising Global Interest in Farmland, 131. 

43 Ibid., 137. 

44 Ibid., 138. 

45 Olivier De Schutter, “How not to Think of Land-Grabbing: Three Critiques of Large-Scale Investments  in Farmland” Journal of Peasant Studies (38) 2 (2011): 255. 

46 Ibid. 

47 Ibid., 250. 

48 “Human Rights Principles to Discipline Land Grabbing” United Nations Special Rapporteur on the right  to food, accessed on April 2, 2011. http://www.srfood.org/index.php/en/component/content/article/127- human-rights-principles-to-discipline-land-grabbing. 

49 Ibid. 

50 Olivier De Schutter, “Large scale land acquisitions and leases: a set of core principles and measures to  address the human rights challenge,” accessed on August 3, 2011,  

http://reliefweb.int/sites/reliefweb.int/files/resources/FA1574FD32C92E67492575D3001AE2FA Full_Report.pdf  

51 Li, “Centering Labour,” 292. 

52 “Civil Society Organizations’ Proposals for the FAO Guidelines on Responsible Governance of Land and  Natural Resources Tenure” FIAN, accessed on April 3, 2011.  

http://www.fian.org/resources/documents/others/cso-proposals-fao-land-guidlines/ 53 Ibid. 

54 “Dakar Appeal Against the Land Grab” Via Campesina, accessed on March 25, 2011.  http://www.viacampesina.org/en/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1040:dakar-appeal against-the-land-grab&catid=23:agrarian-reform&Itemid=36 

55 Ibid. 

56 Institutions are understood in a broad, informal sense and they can take the form of norms, practices or  guidelines.  

57 Ibid. 

58 Ibid., 279. 

59 Raustiala and Victor, “The Regime Complex,” 279. 

60 Deininger et al., Rising Global Interest in Farmland, 137-139. 

61 Ibid. 

62 Gershon Feder and David Feeny, “Land Tenure and Property Rights: Theory and Implications for  Development Policy,” World Bank Economic Review (5) 1 (1991): 135. 

63 De Schutter, “How Not to Think of Land Grabbing,” 265. 

64 David Sadler and Stuart Lloyd, “Neo-liberalising corporate social responsibility: A political economy of  corporate citizenship” Geoforum (40) 4 (2009): 613. 

65 Saturnino M. Borras Jr et al., “The Politics of Biofuels, Land, and Agrarian Change: Editor’s  Introduction” Journal of Peasant Studies (37) 4 (2010): 578. 

66 Karl Polayni, The Great Transformation, (Boston: Beacon Hill Press: 1957), 73. 67 De Schutter, “How Not to Think of Land Grabbing,” 254. 

68 Li, “Centering on Labour,” 293.  

69 Rastialia and Victor, “The Regime Complex,” 280. 

70 De Schutter, “How Not to Think of Land Grabbing,” 210.  

71 J.A., Scholte, “What is Globalization? The Definitional Issue – Again”, Centre for the Study of Globalization and Regionalisation Working Paper (109) 2 (2002): 31.  

72 Klaus Deininger, “Challenges posed by the new wave of farmland investment” The Journal of Peasant  Studies (38) 2 (2011): 217. 

73 Li, “Centering on Labour,”292. 

74 De Schutter, “How Not to Think of Land Grabbing,” 264. 

75 De Schutter, “how Not to Think of Land Grabbing,” 274. 

76 Cotula and Vermeulen, “Deal or No Deal,” 1246.

Previous
Previous

THE DRIVING FACTOR: Songun's Impact on North Korean Foreign Policy

Next
Next

OPINION —EDITORIAL from the U.S. Commission on International Religious Freedom  INTERNATIONAL RELIGIOUS FREEDOM: Why It Matters and How to Protect It